Serveur d'exploration sur le patient édenté

Attention, ce site est en cours de développement !
Attention, site généré par des moyens informatiques à partir de corpus bruts.
Les informations ne sont donc pas validées.

Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden

Identifieur interne : 003522 ( Istex/Corpus ); précédent : 003521; suivant : 003523

Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden

Auteurs : Heikki Hiilamo ; Olli Kangas

Source :

RBID : ISTEX:6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D

Abstract

Debates on welfare reforms have revolved around institutional inertias with the emphasis on institutions as structures. We argue that political discourses work in the same vein and create continuities constraining the array of possible policy options – political frames as carriers of institutional inertia and path dependence. The data are based on political debates on child home care in Finland and Sweden. The ‘trap for women’ frame became dominant in the Swedish discourse, while in Finland ‘freedom to choose’ has been hegemonic. According to the Swedish frame, public day care offers children the best preconditions for later development and enhances social equality, whereas in Finland care at home with all its positive characteristics was contrasted with bureaucratic institutional care. The article highlights how politicians have used these hegemonic discourses to maintain the legitimacy of certain policy options.

Url:
DOI: 10.1017/S0047279409003067

Links to Exploration step

ISTEX:6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D

Le document en format XML

<record>
<TEI wicri:istexFullTextTei="biblStruct">
<teiHeader>
<fileDesc>
<titleStmt>
<title>Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</title>
<author>
<name sortKey="Hiilamo, Heikki" sort="Hiilamo, Heikki" uniqKey="Hiilamo H" first="Heikki" last="Hiilamo">Heikki Hiilamo</name>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>Vice Director, Diaconia University of Applied Sciences/Diak South, Sturenkatu 2, 00510 Helsinki, Finland email: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>E-mail: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
</author>
<author>
<name sortKey="Kangas, Olli" sort="Kangas, Olli" uniqKey="Kangas O" first="Olli" last="Kangas">Olli Kangas</name>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>Research Professor, Social Insurance Institution of Finland, KELA/Research, PO Box 450, 00101 Helsinki, Finland email: olli.kangas@kela.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>E-mail: olli.kangas@kela.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
</author>
</titleStmt>
<publicationStmt>
<idno type="wicri:source">ISTEX</idno>
<idno type="RBID">ISTEX:6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D</idno>
<date when="2009" year="2009">2009</date>
<idno type="doi">10.1017/S0047279409003067</idno>
<idno type="url">https://api.istex.fr/document/6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D/fulltext/pdf</idno>
<idno type="wicri:Area/Istex/Corpus">003522</idno>
<idno type="wicri:explorRef" wicri:stream="Istex" wicri:step="Corpus" wicri:corpus="ISTEX">003522</idno>
</publicationStmt>
<sourceDesc>
<biblStruct>
<analytic>
<title level="a">Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</title>
<author>
<name sortKey="Hiilamo, Heikki" sort="Hiilamo, Heikki" uniqKey="Hiilamo H" first="Heikki" last="Hiilamo">Heikki Hiilamo</name>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>Vice Director, Diaconia University of Applied Sciences/Diak South, Sturenkatu 2, 00510 Helsinki, Finland email: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>E-mail: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
</author>
<author>
<name sortKey="Kangas, Olli" sort="Kangas, Olli" uniqKey="Kangas O" first="Olli" last="Kangas">Olli Kangas</name>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>Research Professor, Social Insurance Institution of Finland, KELA/Research, PO Box 450, 00101 Helsinki, Finland email: olli.kangas@kela.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
<affiliation>
<mods:affiliation>E-mail: olli.kangas@kela.fi</mods:affiliation>
</affiliation>
</author>
</analytic>
<monogr></monogr>
<series>
<title level="j">Journal of Social Policy</title>
<title level="j" type="abbrev">J. Soc. Pol.</title>
<idno type="ISSN">0047-2794</idno>
<idno type="eISSN">1469-7823</idno>
<imprint>
<publisher>Cambridge University Press</publisher>
<pubPlace>Cambridge, UK</pubPlace>
<date type="published" when="2009">2009</date>
<biblScope unit="volume">38</biblScope>
<biblScope unit="issue">3</biblScope>
<biblScope unit="page" from="457">457</biblScope>
<biblScope unit="page" to="475">475</biblScope>
</imprint>
<idno type="ISSN">0047-2794</idno>
</series>
</biblStruct>
</sourceDesc>
<seriesStmt>
<idno type="ISSN">0047-2794</idno>
</seriesStmt>
</fileDesc>
<profileDesc>
<textClass></textClass>
<langUsage>
<language ident="en">en</language>
</langUsage>
</profileDesc>
</teiHeader>
<front>
<div type="abstract">Debates on welfare reforms have revolved around institutional inertias with the emphasis on institutions as structures. We argue that political discourses work in the same vein and create continuities constraining the array of possible policy options – political frames as carriers of institutional inertia and path dependence. The data are based on political debates on child home care in Finland and Sweden. The ‘trap for women’ frame became dominant in the Swedish discourse, while in Finland ‘freedom to choose’ has been hegemonic. According to the Swedish frame, public day care offers children the best preconditions for later development and enhances social equality, whereas in Finland care at home with all its positive characteristics was contrasted with bureaucratic institutional care. The article highlights how politicians have used these hegemonic discourses to maintain the legitimacy of certain policy options.</div>
</front>
</TEI>
<istex>
<corpusName>cambridge</corpusName>
<author>
<json:item>
<name>HEIKKI HIILAMO</name>
<affiliations>
<json:string>Vice Director, Diaconia University of Applied Sciences/Diak South, Sturenkatu 2, 00510 Helsinki, Finland email: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</json:string>
<json:string>E-mail: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</json:string>
</affiliations>
</json:item>
<json:item>
<name>OLLI KANGAS</name>
<affiliations>
<json:string>Research Professor, Social Insurance Institution of Finland, KELA/Research, PO Box 450, 00101 Helsinki, Finland email: olli.kangas@kela.fi</json:string>
<json:string>E-mail: olli.kangas@kela.fi</json:string>
</affiliations>
</json:item>
</author>
<articleId>
<json:string>00306</json:string>
</articleId>
<arkIstex>ark:/67375/6GQ-VQKRR6G9-6</arkIstex>
<language>
<json:string>eng</json:string>
</language>
<originalGenre>
<json:string>research-article</json:string>
</originalGenre>
<abstract>Debates on welfare reforms have revolved around institutional inertias with the emphasis on institutions as structures. We argue that political discourses work in the same vein and create continuities constraining the array of possible policy options – political frames as carriers of institutional inertia and path dependence. The data are based on political debates on child home care in Finland and Sweden. The ‘trap for women’ frame became dominant in the Swedish discourse, while in Finland ‘freedom to choose’ has been hegemonic. According to the Swedish frame, public day care offers children the best preconditions for later development and enhances social equality, whereas in Finland care at home with all its positive characteristics was contrasted with bureaucratic institutional care. The article highlights how politicians have used these hegemonic discourses to maintain the legitimacy of certain policy options.</abstract>
<qualityIndicators>
<refBibsNative>true</refBibsNative>
<abstractWordCount>137</abstractWordCount>
<abstractCharCount>927</abstractCharCount>
<keywordCount>0</keywordCount>
<score>8.644</score>
<pdfWordCount>7303</pdfWordCount>
<pdfCharCount>45547</pdfCharCount>
<pdfVersion>1.3</pdfVersion>
<pdfPageCount>19</pdfPageCount>
<pdfPageSize>430.866 x 646.299 pts</pdfPageSize>
</qualityIndicators>
<title>Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</title>
<pii>
<json:string>S0047279409003067</json:string>
</pii>
<genre>
<json:string>research-article</json:string>
</genre>
<host>
<title>Journal of Social Policy</title>
<language>
<json:string>unknown</json:string>
</language>
<issn>
<json:string>0047-2794</json:string>
</issn>
<eissn>
<json:string>1469-7823</json:string>
</eissn>
<publisherId>
<json:string>JSP</json:string>
</publisherId>
<volume>38</volume>
<issue>3</issue>
<pages>
<first>457</first>
<last>475</last>
<total>19</total>
</pages>
<genre>
<json:string>journal</json:string>
</genre>
</host>
<ark>
<json:string>ark:/67375/6GQ-VQKRR6G9-6</json:string>
</ark>
<publicationDate>2009</publicationDate>
<copyrightDate>2009</copyrightDate>
<doi>
<json:string>10.1017/S0047279409003067</json:string>
</doi>
<id>6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D</id>
<score>1</score>
<fulltext>
<json:item>
<extension>pdf</extension>
<original>true</original>
<mimetype>application/pdf</mimetype>
<uri>https://api.istex.fr/document/6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D/fulltext/pdf</uri>
</json:item>
<json:item>
<extension>zip</extension>
<original>false</original>
<mimetype>application/zip</mimetype>
<uri>https://api.istex.fr/document/6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D/fulltext/zip</uri>
</json:item>
<json:item>
<extension>txt</extension>
<original>false</original>
<mimetype>text/plain</mimetype>
<uri>https://api.istex.fr/document/6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D/fulltext/txt</uri>
</json:item>
<istex:fulltextTEI uri="https://api.istex.fr/document/6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D/fulltext/tei">
<teiHeader>
<fileDesc>
<titleStmt>
<title level="a">Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</title>
</titleStmt>
<publicationStmt>
<authority>ISTEX</authority>
<publisher scheme="https://publisher-list.data.istex.fr">Cambridge University Press</publisher>
<pubPlace>Cambridge, UK</pubPlace>
<availability>
<licence>
<p>Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009</p>
</licence>
<p scheme="https://loaded-corpus.data.istex.fr/ark:/67375/XBH-G3RCRD03-V">cambridge</p>
</availability>
<date>2009</date>
</publicationStmt>
<notesStmt>
<note type="research-article" scheme="https://content-type.data.istex.fr/ark:/67375/XTP-1JC4F85T-7">research-article</note>
<note type="journal" scheme="https://publication-type.data.istex.fr/ark:/67375/JMC-0GLKJH51-B">journal</note>
</notesStmt>
<sourceDesc>
<biblStruct type="inbook">
<analytic>
<title level="a">Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</title>
<author xml:id="author-0000">
<persName>
<forename type="first">HEIKKI</forename>
<surname>HIILAMO</surname>
</persName>
<email>heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</email>
<affiliation>Vice Director, Diaconia University of Applied Sciences/Diak South, Sturenkatu 2, 00510 Helsinki, Finland email: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</affiliation>
</author>
<author xml:id="author-0001">
<persName>
<forename type="first">OLLI</forename>
<surname>KANGAS</surname>
</persName>
<email>olli.kangas@kela.fi</email>
<affiliation>Research Professor, Social Insurance Institution of Finland, KELA/Research, PO Box 450, 00101 Helsinki, Finland email: olli.kangas@kela.fi</affiliation>
</author>
<idno type="istex">6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D</idno>
<idno type="ark">ark:/67375/6GQ-VQKRR6G9-6</idno>
<idno type="DOI">10.1017/S0047279409003067</idno>
<idno type="PII">S0047279409003067</idno>
<idno type="article-id">00306</idno>
</analytic>
<monogr>
<title level="j">Journal of Social Policy</title>
<title level="j" type="abbrev">J. Soc. Pol.</title>
<idno type="pISSN">0047-2794</idno>
<idno type="eISSN">1469-7823</idno>
<idno type="publisher-id">JSP</idno>
<imprint>
<publisher>Cambridge University Press</publisher>
<pubPlace>Cambridge, UK</pubPlace>
<date type="published" when="2009"></date>
<biblScope unit="volume">38</biblScope>
<biblScope unit="issue">3</biblScope>
<biblScope unit="page" from="457">457</biblScope>
<biblScope unit="page" to="475">475</biblScope>
</imprint>
</monogr>
</biblStruct>
</sourceDesc>
</fileDesc>
<profileDesc>
<creation>
<date>2009</date>
</creation>
<langUsage>
<language ident="en">en</language>
</langUsage>
<abstract style="normal">
<p>Debates on welfare reforms have revolved around institutional inertias with the emphasis on institutions as structures. We argue that political discourses work in the same vein and create continuities constraining the array of possible policy options – political frames as carriers of institutional inertia and path dependence. The data are based on political debates on child home care in Finland and Sweden. The ‘trap for women’ frame became dominant in the Swedish discourse, while in Finland ‘freedom to choose’ has been hegemonic. According to the Swedish frame, public day care offers children the best preconditions for later development and enhances social equality, whereas in Finland care at home with all its positive characteristics was contrasted with bureaucratic institutional care. The article highlights how politicians have used these hegemonic discourses to maintain the legitimacy of certain policy options.</p>
</abstract>
</profileDesc>
<revisionDesc>
<change when="2009">Published</change>
</revisionDesc>
</teiHeader>
</istex:fulltextTEI>
</fulltext>
<metadata>
<istex:metadataXml wicri:clean="corpus cambridge not found" wicri:toSee="no header">
<istex:xmlDeclaration>version="1.0" encoding="US-ASCII"</istex:xmlDeclaration>
<istex:docType PUBLIC="-//NLM//DTD Journal Publishing DTD v2.2 20060430//EN" URI="journalpublishing.dtd" name="istex:docType"></istex:docType>
<istex:document>
<article dtd-version="2.2" article-type="research-article">
<front>
<journal-meta>
<journal-id journal-id-type="publisher-id">JSP</journal-id>
<journal-title>Journal of Social Policy</journal-title>
<abbrev-journal-title>J. Soc. Pol.</abbrev-journal-title>
<issn pub-type="ppub">0047-2794</issn>
<issn pub-type="epub">1469-7823</issn>
<publisher>
<publisher-name>Cambridge University Press</publisher-name>
<publisher-loc>Cambridge, UK</publisher-loc>
</publisher>
</journal-meta>
<article-meta>
<article-id pub-id-type="doi">10.1017/S0047279409003067</article-id>
<article-id pub-id-type="pii">S0047279409003067</article-id>
<article-id pub-id-type="publisher-id">00306</article-id>
<title-group>
<article-title>Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</article-title>
<alt-title alt-title-type="left-running">HEIKKI HIILAMO AND OLLI KANGAS</alt-title>
<alt-title alt-title-type="right-running">TRAP FOR WOMEN OR FREEDOM TO CHOOSE?</alt-title>
</title-group>
<contrib-group>
<contrib contrib-type="author">
<name>
<surname>HIILAMO</surname>
<given-names>HEIKKI</given-names>
</name>
<xref ref-type="aff" rid="aff001">*</xref>
</contrib>
<contrib contrib-type="author">
<name>
<surname>KANGAS</surname>
<given-names>OLLI</given-names>
</name>
<xref ref-type="aff" rid="aff002">**</xref>
</contrib>
</contrib-group>
<aff id="aff001">
<label>*</label>
Vice Director,
<institution>Diaconia University of Applied Sciences/Diak South</institution>
,
<addr-line>Sturenkatu 2</addr-line>
,
<addr-line>00510 Helsinki</addr-line>
,
<country>Finland</country>
email:
<email xlink:href="heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi">heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</email>
</aff>
<aff id="aff002">
<label>**</label>
Research Professor,
<institution>Social Insurance Institution of Finland</institution>
,
<addr-line>KELA/Research</addr-line>
,
<addr-line>PO Box 450</addr-line>
,
<addr-line>00101 Helsinki</addr-line>
,
<country>Finland</country>
email:
<email xlink:href="olli.kangas@kela.fi">olli.kangas@kela.fi</email>
</aff>
<pub-date pub-type="epub-ppub">
<month>07</month>
<year>2009</year>
</pub-date>
<volume>38</volume>
<issue>3</issue>
<fpage seq="8">457</fpage>
<lpage>475</lpage>
<permissions>
<copyright-statement>Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009</copyright-statement>
<copyright-year>2009</copyright-year>
<copyright-holder>Cambridge University Press</copyright-holder>
</permissions>
<abstract abstract-type="normal">
<title>Abstract</title>
<p>Debates on welfare reforms have revolved around institutional inertias with the emphasis on institutions as structures. We argue that political discourses work in the same vein and create continuities constraining the array of possible policy options – political frames as carriers of institutional inertia and path dependence. The data are based on political debates on child home care in Finland and Sweden. The ‘trap for women’ frame became dominant in the Swedish discourse, while in Finland ‘freedom to choose’ has been hegemonic. According to the Swedish frame, public day care offers children the best preconditions for later development and enhances social equality, whereas in Finland care at home with all its positive characteristics was contrasted with bureaucratic institutional care. The article highlights how politicians have used these hegemonic discourses to maintain the legitimacy of certain policy options.</p>
</abstract>
<counts>
<page-count count="19"></page-count>
</counts>
<custom-meta-wrap>
<custom-meta>
<meta-name>pdf</meta-name>
<meta-value>S0047279409003067a.pdf</meta-value>
</custom-meta>
<custom-meta>
<meta-name>dispart</meta-name>
<meta-value>Article</meta-value>
</custom-meta>
</custom-meta-wrap>
</article-meta>
</front>
<body>
<sec id="sec1">
<title>Introduction: from structures to ideas</title>
<p>Historical development of social policy has been explained from numerous perspectives. The first array of comparative research regarded the welfare state as a functional solution to big structural changes in society. Whether it was about industrialisation, economic growth, class structure or maturation of capitalism, scholars interpreted the development of social policy as an automatic functional response to these structural transformations.</p>
<p>The problem with these structural-functionalistic theories was that they were not able to explain differences between developed countries. As a result, researchers shifted their gaze to political power, and political actors became central for understanding national variation in social policies (Korpi,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref37">1978</xref>
; Korpi and Palme,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref38">2003</xref>
). While the power resource theory has been successfully used in comparative welfare research, lately it has been challenged by varying forms of institutionalism emphasising the role of social institutions (Steinmo
<italic>et al</italic>
.,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref63">1992</xref>
; Thelen,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref66">2004</xref>
). A common denominator in the variants of the institutional school is that previous decisions are seen as restricting subsequent ones and putting policies on specific tracks, creating path dependencies in policy-making (Mahoney,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref50">2000</xref>
; Streeck and Thelen,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref64">2004</xref>
; Thelen,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref66">2004</xref>
).</p>
<p>In recent years, the emphasis has shifted from the structural view of institutions as structures towards more cultural interpretations (Cambell,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref8">1998</xref>
; Lieberman,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref45">2002</xref>
; Schmidt,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref61">2002</xref>
; Pfau-Effinger,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref55">2005</xref>
). In these ‘ideational’ explanations, ideas constitute paradigms that form the basis for cognitive and ontological assumptions, meaning that political ideas can also be regarded as path dependent: we see what we are used to seeing, and in this way political discourses contribute to path dependency (de Saussure,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref60">1974</xref>
; Fairclough,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref14">1989</xref>
,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref15">1992</xref>
).</p>
<p>Ideational path dependency relates to a concept of hegemony according to which certain frames or ways of thinking are ‘naturalised’ and achieve the status of common sense, and these frames become invisible even for the actors that launched them (Bourdieu,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref6">2003</xref>
). We can also speak of hegemonic discourses in the sense that if policy-makers wish to change something in society, the structures and content of thinking must be changed (Gramsci,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref24">1971</xref>
; Laclau and Mouffe,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref41">1985</xref>
; Foucault,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref17">1986</xref>
). Therefore, the ‘struggle of interpretation’ (Pfau-Effinger,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref55">2005</xref>
) preceding institutional change is of crucial importance. The actors who, at a constitutional moment (Elster,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref11">1993</xref>
: 34), are able to establish the frame to be used exercise decisive power on the motivational basis of policy debates; they shape the political beliefs not only of the current cohorts but also of future policy-makers (Spector and Kitsuse,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref62">1989</xref>
; Lieberman,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref45">2002</xref>
; Beland,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref2">2005</xref>
). Discursive ideas can crystallise; that is, they can be interpreted as ideational structures and they may serve as intermediate variables between material socio-economic (class) structures on the one hand and policy outcomes on the other.</p>
<p>At the political level, a constant hegemonic battle exists, and politicians must frequently renew their discourses (Majone,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref51">1989</xref>
: 31). In this battle, elites frame their proposals in such a way that their initiatives appear to constitute the best solution to actual social problems. Proposals must be packaged in normatively acceptable ways. Instead of referring to specific group interests, parties must refer to more widely accepted cultural values, such as freedom, social justice and equality. Actors also manipulate public sentiments to serve their own ends (Gamson and Modigliani,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref19">1987</xref>
,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref20">1989</xref>
). It is here that political framing becomes crucial. Political struggles are fought in symbolic arenas through the use of phrases, metaphors and symbols. As individual voters are unable to take into account
<italic>all possible</italic>
aspects and collect
<italic>all possible</italic>
information on different policy options, they react to these metaphors and use them as shortcuts for their political choices.</p>
<p>The aim of this article is to analyse whether the discourses that political actors in Finland and in Sweden have used can explain the differences in family policy outcomes: in our case, cash for child care. Our emphasis is on the framing: that is, on those verbal tricks that actors use to institutionalise their discourse into material existence. We argue that to understand differences in policy-making properly it is not enough to refer to differences in social structures or political power; instead, we must also consider the ideational framework that ruled out some options and opened possibilities for other choices. In this article, we are interested in the political usage of discourses, meaning that we do not intend to scrutinise whether cash for care
<italic>de facto</italic>
enhances freedom or constitutes a trap (for that discussion, see Morgan and Zippel,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref52">2003</xref>
; Haataja and Nyberg,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref25">2006</xref>
).</p>
<p>When emphasising as we have that discourses give meaning and interpretation to social phenomena, we do not wish to refute the importance of social or class structures; our approach is dialectical (or interactionist). In other words, the ideas that can ‘become effective forces in history’ (Weber,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref69">1989</xref>
[1904–5]: 90) must be implemented by predominant bearers, or as Geertz succinctly writes: ideas must ‘be carried by powerful social groups to have powerful social effects; someone must revere them, celebrate them, defend them, impose them. They have to be institutionalised in order to find not just an intellectual existence in society, but, so to speak, material as well’ (1972: 314). Thus, while political discourse is linked to social structures, it is not entirely socially determined. On the other hand, although discursive frames contribute to our understanding of social structures, social structures cannot be reduced to mere discourses.</p>
<p>The method we use is content analysis focused on dominant political discourses. When trying to sell their message, political actors strategically choose language that supports their interpretation of social problems. In this process, symbols resonating with important cultural values and sentiments are the most effective (Geertz,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref21">1972</xref>
: 126–31; Giddens,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref22">1991</xref>
: 35–47). From our data, we were able to discern some evergreen themes that have been constantly used in both Finnish and Swedish political rhetoric (see also Leira,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref44">2002</xref>
; Ellingsæter,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref10">2007</xref>
): freedom, justice and equality. In the light of these core values, politicians debate about five subthemes: the women's ‘double burden’, children's welfare, cost-effectiveness, labour supply and fertility.</p>
<p>The structure of the article is as follows. In the next section, we give our motivations for our approach and for the choice of the two countries and data used. Thereafter follows an analysis on the struggle for hegemony and the formation of the dominant frames. The final section discusses and summarises the central findings.</p>
</sec>
<sec id="sec2">
<title>The cases and data</title>
<p>The creation of cash-for-care (home care allowance) in Finland and Sweden offers interesting possibilities for studying the use of political discourses in promoting policy measures. First, Finland and Sweden are usually classified as countries belonging to the Nordic welfare model (Timonen,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref67">2003</xref>
); however, they differ with regard to child-care policies (Bergqvist
<italic>et al</italic>
.,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref4">1999</xref>
; Sainsbury,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref58">1999</xref>
; Hiilamo,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref28">2002</xref>
; Ferrarini,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref16">2006</xref>
; Gornick and Mayers,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref23">2003</xref>
). In Sweden, while allowance for families with small children has constituted solely parents' insurance and public day care, the Reinfeldt non-socialist government (2006–) implemented care allowance in 2008. In Finland, by contrast, each child has a right to day care, but cash-for-care is payable to those parents who do not use their right to public day care (see
<xref ref-type="table" rid="tab1">Table 1</xref>
).
<table-wrap position="float" id="tab1">
<label>TABLE 1.</label>
<caption>
<p>Development of cash-for-care schemes (CCS) in Finland and in Sweden</p>
</caption>
<graphic xlink:href="S0047279409003067_tab1" mime-subtype="gif"></graphic>
</table-wrap>
</p>
<p>Second, the relationship between discourse and social structure is dialectical. As Geertz (
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref21">1972</xref>
: 314) argued, some strong groups must adhere to ideas in order to make ideas politically effective, or to give them ‘material existence’. At the same time, however, hegemonic discourses can fortify the power position of those who adhere to them or the initial owner of the idea. Finland and Sweden are good examples of these power struggles. In Sweden, the Social Democratic Party (SAP) took the leading position as early as the 1930s. Even though non-socialist parties have occasionally been in power, social democracy has conditioned political activity, and social democratic hegemony has framed the non-socialist political discussion (Lundberg,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref47">2003</xref>
). In Finland, by contrast, the Agrarian Party (since 1965 the Centre Party) had the political upper hand up to the mid-1960s, after which the Social Democratic Party (SDP) became the senior partner in coalition cabinets. Nevertheless, the SDP never achieved the same hegemonic position that the SAP had in Sweden (Lane and Ersson,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref42">2002</xref>
).</p>
<p>Third, due to the differences in power constellations, there were differences in the political representation of feminist ideas. While in Sweden women's labour market interests were mobilised chiefly via the SAP, in Finland many other groups were in play (Tyyskä,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref68">1995</xref>
). The interests of rural women were voiced through the Agrarian/Centre Party, while those of the urban working female labour force were voiced by a minimum of four different parties. Thus, women's voices in politics were more diversified in Finland than in Sweden: in the latter, the Social Democratic women's movement dominated the political discourse, whereas in the former the agrarian-bourgeois voice was the loudest.</p>
<p>Fourth, the political power differences in Finland and Sweden have had an impact upon the hegemonic frames within which family policy was debated. In principle, our story of cash-for-care could have been told from the structural-political perspective: as a result of structural factors in society, agrarian political influence has been stronger in Finland. End of story? Not quite! Structural constraints as such are not directly transformed into politics. Somebody must first define ‘structural needs’ and what is necessary to meet them, and in this ‘politics of need interpretation’ political framing becomes important.</p>
<p>The data we use in our analyses are partially derived from parliamentary proceedings, party programmes and other family policy publications produced by political actors. We mainly concentrate on the post-World War II discourse that the dominant political actors used. In addition to primary sources, we draw on earlier detailed historical studies on Swedish (Hinnfors,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref30">1992</xref>
; Hiilamo,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref28">2002</xref>
; Lundqvist,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref48">2007</xref>
) and Finnish (Sakaranaho,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref59">1992</xref>
; Anttonen,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref1">1999</xref>
; Hiilamo,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref28">2002</xref>
) family policies.</p>
<p>Before we move on to analyse the discourses, some clarification of the sequential order of policy debates and reforms is necessary.
<xref ref-type="table" rid="tab1">Table 1</xref>
summarises the central political constellations and lines of demarcation both between and within parties. As the table shows, in both countries there have been changes in opinions, and political parties have changed their orientations. In the subsequent sections, we show what kind of discursive frames were used for motivating those shifts.</p>
</sec>
<sec id="sec3">
<title>Political discourses</title>
<sec id="sec3-1">
<title>Justice and freedom of choice</title>
<p>In the 1930s and 1940s, the Finnish Social Democrats had a positive attitude towards the ‘mother's wage’ (Sulkunen,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref65">1989</xref>
: 126–7), and the female SDP Members of Parliament introduced a bill on the subject in 1947 (Petitionary motion no. 288/1947). However, the motion did not lead to further measures and the SDP gradually lost interest in the issue, whereas the Agrarian Party started to champion the mother's wage (Tyyskä,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref68">1995</xref>
: 155–6; Nygård,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref53">2003</xref>
). Cash-for-care served the interests of the rural population, which traditionally cared for their children at home. However, instead of referring to the group-specific interest, the party framed its demands by references to social justice (families who do not use subsidised municipal day care should also have right to subsidies) and freedom of choice between different forms of care. The latter theme was also important for the Conservatives, for whom cash-for-care offered a possibility for subsidising those families employing a nanny at home or utilising private suppliers (Ervasti,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref13">1996</xref>
).</p>
<p>The question of the mother's wage came up in Finland again in 1972, with the dispute over the Child Day Care Act. Although the Centrists and the Conservatives insisted on cash-for-care, they had changed their terminology: ‘care allowance’ was now under discussion instead of ‘mother's wage’. The rhetorical reasoning was that ‘care allowance’ stressed the right to choose and sounded gender-neutral, while ‘mother's wage’ was clearly gendered and emphasised women's domestic duties (Tyyskä,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref68">1995</xref>
: 111–12). The political left pursued the development of municipal day care and criticised the care allowance as merely the transfer of income from wage earners to farmers (who take care of their own children anyway) and high-income groups (who employ nannies at home), thus making the system socially unjust. In addition, according to the left, the allowance restricts rather than enhances real freedom of choice, with mothers ending up staying locked in their traditional roles.</p>
<p>On the non-socialist side, the concepts of justice and freedom were interpreted differently. The Finnish bourgeois parties declared that work at home either is as valuable as work outside the home, or indeed even more valuable, which the public authorities should recognise. Care allowance would be the best recognition. As for the justice principle, tax-paying families who do not use publicly supported day care would suffer in comparison to those who do. In the eyes of the non-socialists, cash-for-care was a remedy for this injustice. Perhaps their most powerful adage has been ‘freedom of choice’: parents themselves know better than the state bureaucrats what is best for their children. Freedom of choice was thus framed as a battle between the family and a heartless bureaucracy (for example, Petitionary motion no. 1493/1982). Since the socialists could not seize the bourgeois discursive frame, they had to accept cash-for-care as an alternative to municipal care. The Act on Home Care Allowance was implemented in 1982, and since then the left has been unable to challenge the dominant discourse or to give it any alternative content.</p>
<p>In Sweden, while the rhetorical frames were to some extent the same as in Finland, the party profiles were more volatile (
<xref ref-type="table" rid="tab1">Table 1</xref>
). The SAP adopted care allowance in its political agenda in the early 1960s when compensation for child care being paid out to parents was discussed. With the help of this compensation, the mother could decide whether or not to care for the small child herself at home. The rationale was that cash-for-care would also allow working-class men the right to ‘a housewife’, a right the middle classes already had (Lindberg,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref49">2001</xref>
). In a parliamentary discussion on cash-for-care in 1965, the chair of the SAP Women's Union supported the allowance (Preliminary debate protocol 4 20/1;
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref74">1965</xref>
: 27).</p>
<p>In light of the present-day political constellations, the opponents of the cash-for-care scheme came from a surprising camp: the Conservatives. The ideology of the Conservative Party called for restricting the role of the public sector to a minimum. Too extensive a social sector would lead to dependence on allowances, and therefore citizens had to be guaranteed both freedom from state patronage and freedom of choice between different forms of child care. The negative concept of freedom – that is, freedom from the state – is emphasised in the party programme of 1963: ‘We find it, in principle, unpleasant that the state should pay for the natural tasks [involved] in parenthood. Such a step would mean a further step towards general socialisation.’</p>
<p>On certain issues, the ideology of the Swedish Centre Party resembled the ideas of the Conservative Party. The Centrists also supported a kind of minimal welfare state; however, in their vision, benefits should be flat-rate and universal. In addition to this compulsory basic security, the state should not interfere in organising social benefits (Hinnfors,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref30">1992</xref>
: 70–2) but only guarantee the basic prerequisites of the cornerstones of society: family and small entrepreneurship. Cash-for-care had an important role to play in fulfilling this task, as it would acknowledge the work of mothers. Thus, women doing different work, either in paid labour or at home, would have the same status. In this respect, the vocabularies of the Finnish and Swedish Centre Parties were the same.</p>
<p>In Sweden, the Conservatives' family policy was based on tax deductions until 1972, after which the party gradually started to favour subsidies for public day care while simultaneously demanding subsidies to private day care on the basis of equal treatment. Little by little, the party began to emphasise cash-for-care, and its political stance converged with that of the Centre Party. In their demands, these two parties emphasised justice among alternative forms of care: there should more than just one alternative, municipal day care supported by tax revenue. Monetary compensation should also be offered to families whose children were not in public day-care centres. This position became the parties' guiding rhetorical theme.</p>
<p>The SAP also totally changed both its opinions and rhetoric on allowance. Freedom of choice and justice remained, but now with a new meaning. First, the SAP depicted day-care centres as the most just alternative: by offering stimuli, these centres increased equality between children coming from different backgrounds. Second, public day care offered women real alternatives between working life and home. When hitting back against the Conservatives and Centrists, the Social Democrats argued that freedom of choice guaranteed by the cash-for-care system would pertain only to women with well-paid husbands, not to women on low income or single mothers. When the non-socialist coalition cabinet implemented cash-for-care in 1994, the SAP fiercely opposed the scheme, introducing the slogan ‘a trap for women’ (SOU,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref79">1994</xref>
: 25).</p>
<p>When the SAP formed a new cabinet in 1994, one of its first tasks was to abolish the cash-for-care programme established a few months earlier. At the time of writing (spring 2008), the non-socialist cabinet implemented the system anew, now named as
<italic>Freedom of Choice Reform</italic>
, referring to precisely the same frames as before: parents should have the right to choose, as they know better than ‘experts in Stockholm’ what is best for the family (Larsson and Hägglund,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref43">2007</xref>
). Furthermore, the
<italic>Freedom of Choice Reform</italic>
was motivated by municipal democracy: many municipalities wished to implement the allowance. Cleverly enough, the cabinet chose the Finnish gradual approach starting at the municipal level, meaning that if the next SAP government tries to abolish the allowance, it will have to fight resistance from local authorities.</p>
</sec>
<sec id="sec3-2">
<title>Women's double burden</title>
<p>The Finnish 1947 motion recognised women's double burden and stated that the ‘mother's wage’ would help all the ‘mothers exhausted by a heavy work load’ to avoid the double responsibility. Women should be given the option of being full-time mothers. As this idea of decommodification faded away from the rhetoric of the left, it started to live its own life in the rhetoric of the Centre Party. The Christian Democrats and the Rural Party used similar arguments. The Conservative Party found a solution to women's double burden in ‘the possibility of choice’. Differences in the emphasis between the Conservatives and the other non-socialist parties can be explained by their different constituencies. The Conservatives gathered votes from the well-educated white-collar employees who had problems in combining paid work and family. In contrast, for the core voters of the Rural Party and the Centre, this issue has not been that pressing (Kangas,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref36">1986</xref>
).</p>
<p>The Rural Party vigorously emphasised women's biological role and the value of work done at home. An interesting difference between the Centre and the Rural Parties is that up to the early 1980s both parties explicitly insisted that the
<italic>mother</italic>
should have the possibility of staying at home. Since the mid-1980s, the Centre has changed its rhetoric, becoming more gender-neutral by demanding that
<italic>one of the parents</italic>
should be able to stay at home. By contrast, the Rural Party still emphasises traditional family roles and, together with the Christian Democrats, demands both the recognition (Frazer,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref18">2003</xref>
) and the rewarding of the work families are doing at home.</p>
<p>The traditional family model and housework done by women were also supported by the Swedish Social Democrats until the 1960s. Work inside the home was seen as at least as rewarding as work outside the home. The view was that it is not a particularly great privilege for working-class women to go to the factory and drill holes in small pieces of metal all day. By comparison, housework seemed like paradise (Eriksson,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref12">1964</xref>
). However, there were variations in the opinions. Already by the 1930s, Alva Myrdal demanded policy measures to help women combine motherhood and paid work, a combination she regarded necessary for gender equality (Hirdman,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref33">1997</xref>
,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref35">2006</xref>
; Björnberg,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref5">2002</xref>
). Although her ideas did not receive an immediate response, in the 1960s and early 1970s they gradually gained a hegemonic position within the SAP that turned out to favour municipal day care.</p>
<p>A book published by the SAP Women's Organisation in 1972 about the family and future family policy marked a turning point in social democratic family policy (Hirdman,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref34">1998</xref>
). It proposed a radical model for a new society that would be based on a six-hour working day, acknowledging equal rights and obligations for men and women to participate in working life and in caring for the home and children. Through its proposal, the book attempted to solve the problem of women's double role by guaranteeing both parents the possibility of fulfilling it. According to the SAP, cash-for-care was unsuitable for the vision of a new society aiming at gender equality in working life and parenthood. Home care belonged to the society of the past. Consequently, in this frame the dual-earner and dual-carer model began to materialise, and the dichotomous concept of working versus caring mother was rejected.</p>
<p>Both the Swedish Conservative Party and the Centre Party were dubious about the socialist family model of two wage earners, a model that they considered harmful to children, family and society at large. However, this argument appeared old-fashioned and toothless compared to the future-oriented emancipatory politics of the SAP. To increase its political appeal, the Centre therefore changed its slogan at the beginning of the 1980s. The name of the previous home care allowance (vårdnadsbidrag) was changed to home ‘care compensation’ (vårdnadsersättning) (Hinnfors,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref30">1992</xref>
: 167). The connotation of the term is different: Allowance (
<italic>bidrag</italic>
) is given as an addition to something – that is, a gift from the state – while
<italic>ersättning</italic>
is rightful compensation for something to which one is entitled. With this interpretation, cash-for-care would also be the best way to solve women's double burden: household duties would receive their status as valuable work. Thus, in both countries, the Christian Democrats and the Centre demanded the recognition of home care as a legitimate activity.</p>
<p>The early 1970s came to be a turning point or a kind of Elsterian (Elster,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref11">1993</xref>
) ‘constitutional moment’ in Swedish family policy. Until that time, the SAP and the Conservatives in particular had been ambivalent in their family policy orientations. By the 1970s, party fissures had been healed. The parties both altered their stances and their in-party hegemonic concepts, the Social Democrats being supporters of public day care and the Conservatives insisting on state subsidises for alternative care forms. Subsequent political generations in their between-party campaigns on hegemony have followed these rhetorical frames.</p>
</sec>
<sec id="sec3-3">
<title>Child welfare</title>
<p>Politicians thematically combine arguments on child welfare with a solution for women's double role. Usually the rhetorical frames, in which the solution to the ‘double burden’ was housework, also emphasised the favourableness of home care for children (Financial motion 569/1981). This kind of home-centred vision had more bite in Finland than in Sweden. For Finland, ‘the word’ also exerted its power: advocates of cash-for-care contrasted public institutional care with home care. This contrast implicitly linked cold, inhuman bureaucracy and rigidity to public day care, while home care represented all positive values, such as love, closeness, security and warmth. In Finland, the non-socialist parties succeeded with this framing over that of the left and, finally, the leftist vision of public day care was criticised as a DDR-kind of totalitarian education. The Swedish non-socialists tried a similar linguistic trick, and the Conservatives in particular criticised the extension of day care as a form of neglect of child welfare (Burestam Linder,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref7">1983</xref>
).</p>
<p>Many arguments referring to medical problems resulting from day care were used for home care in both countries. Again, this discourse got a stronger footing in Finland, whereas the dominant Swedish frame portrayed universal and public day care as the best conditions for children's welfare and overall development. We can trace this positive view back to the social democratic idea of social engineering and the planning of a good society in which child care was arranged collectively, and trained personnel had to have the primary responsibility for the well-being of the children (Hirdman,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref32">1989</xref>
). Day-care centres thus also fulfilled the objective of equality: children from different backgrounds were given equal chances. The ideas are echoed in later expert reports: ‘child care provision accessible to everybody should provide a means of compensation for children with scarce resources at home’ (SOU,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref78">1972</xref>
: 34; Lundqvist,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref48">2007</xref>
: 172–9).</p>
<p>In this Swedish frame, public day care combined the children's interests with equality: equality between rich and poor children or men and women (Hatje,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref27">1974</xref>
; Hirdman,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref31">1988</xref>
). The
<italic>Freedom of Choice Reform</italic>
does not directly challenge this frame. It emphasises the need for well-functioning municipal day care, while at the same time indirectly finding fault with it: families must be guaranteed flexible solutions to spend more time together instead of parents being in paid labour and children in public day care.</p>
</sec>
<sec id="sec3-4">
<title>Cost-effectiveness</title>
<p>The Finnish cash-for-care system was initiated gradually in the 1960s through municipal experiments. The rationale was that municipalities usually tried to avoid investments in facilities and costs for personnel. The cost issue was spelled out in the very first parliamentary motion, emphasising that the mother's wage would be a cheap alternative because ‘considerable costs for each child have to be paid in institutional settings and employees must be paid salaries’ (Petitionary motion 288/1947). While left-wing politicians later tried to push this theme into the background, it had increasing importance in the non-socialist rhetoric, which stressed that facilities and personnel are necessary for institutions; at home they are available free of charge, and therefore home care is ultimately the cheapest alternative. In addition to the direct costs, public day care also incurs a lot of indirect costs, since children in day-care centres are more prone to illness, which in turn produces health care costs and loss of production in society as a whole.</p>
<p>In 1990, the Finnish Conservative-SDP cabinet (1987–91) implemented the unconditional right to day care for children under the age of three. When the economic recession hit Finland in the early 1990s, the Centre-Right cabinet (1991–96) feared that the Act would considerably increase social expenses if all parents exercised their rights. In order to circumvent this, the representatives of the Centre (the leading partner in the bourgeois coalition cabinet) insisted on improving cash-for-care benefits, which would lessen the demand for day care and reduce the expenses incurred by municipalities. The depth of the recession fortified this line of reasoning, and the Centre Party proposed further improvements in cash-for-care allowances to save public resources and to reduce unemployment and the use of income support. Instead of being registered as unemployed or relying on social assistance, parents would take care of their children. In the midst of the crisis, care allowance appeared to be a good way of achieving savings ‘without any tears’. The cabinet improved the real value of the allowance by 30 per cent, but the subsequent SDP-led cabinet (1996–1999) cut allowances by more than 20 per cent in 1996 (Hiilamo,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref29">2003</xref>
: 139). At that time, various social democratic initiatives questioned the whole cash-for-care system.
<xref ref-type="fn" rid="fn1">
<sup>1</sup>
</xref>
These initiatives, however, were heavily criticised by the general public, which threatened the overall popularity of the party to such an extent that the initiatives had to be abandoned within a very short time.</p>
<p>As with their Finnish sister parties, the Centre and the Conservatives in Sweden considered home care to be much cheaper than public day-care centres. This line of reasoning also continued post-1994 when the SAP government had abolished the cash-for-care system. Among their criticisms was the comparison between costs for different forms of care (motion no 98/1997: Ub211). Cost-effectiveness was also centrally posed in the ‘Freedom of choice’ reform, according to which a place in public child-care costs as much as SKR 100,000 a year, whereas the tax-free home allowance costs as little as SKR 3,000 a month (Socialdepartementet,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref76">2007</xref>
).</p>
<p>Avoiding excessive social spending has been an underlying meta-theme in Finnish politics, where two modes of policy-making have been contrasted against each other: ‘politics of distribution’ (
<italic>jakopolitiikka</italic>
) and ‘politics of responsibility’ (
<italic>vastuupolitiikka</italic>
). The former refers to a politician promising benefits without considering their costs, while the latter refers to the responsible politician who first thinks about the costs and only then decides whether to implement a reform. The bourgeois parlance portrays the SDP, in particular, as a party of distribution. In Swedish policy-making, such frames have not been as effective as these in Finland. These differences in discursive meta-frames have had important ramifications for the manoeuvrability of the Social Democrats. In Sweden, the SAP has been able to counteract the bourgeois home-care proposals by promising longer parental leave with gender-equalising legislation and by promising improvements in the income-loss compensation in the form of parental insurance (Sahlin,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref57">2007</xref>
). If such an insurance were implemented, the need for cash-for-care would be nullified by a compensatory device. Meanwhile, in Finland, the ‘politics of responsibility’ frame prevented the SDP from using the corresponding strategy.</p>
</sec>
<sec id="sec3-5">
<title>Labour supply</title>
<p>One important structural factor that has divided Swedish and Finnish politics and fortified the dominant national frames is the demand for and supply of labour. The supply of labour illuminates dialectical relationships between the structural context and political discourse. While the structural context supports the dominant modes of thinking, hegemonic discourse constrains the political options available for reacting to structural problems.</p>
<p>A committee set up in the mid-1960s to analyse the future of the Swedish national economy forecast a labour shortage in Sweden. According to the committee report (SOU,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref77">1966</xref>
: 59), a severe and long-lasting recession would threaten the economy if the problem of labour shortage could not be solved. As mothers caring for their children presented industry with a potential pool of labour, women's labour force participation and the family model of two breadwinners quickly started to expand. The change in the family model required that day care be available. The fastest and most effective solution was the public day-care centre system, whereby one pre-school teacher was able to care for several children. According to this social democratic interpretation, the liberated labour force was at the disposal of industry, creating wealth and prosperity for Sweden.</p>
<p>By comparison, the situation in Finland was completely different. The country had an abundance of surplus labour due to a diminishing agricultural sector, and cash-for-care was seen as a solution to the country's unemployment problem. By staying at home, those caring for their children with the help of a home care allowance not only gave other people the possibility of work but also gave them the opportunity to have an important impact on the offspring of their society. The hidden message was that if there is a shortage of work, women must give way to male employees. One can ponder what will happen in Finland if unemployment turns into a labour shortage as forecast. If that were to happen, one important element of the structural cornerstones of the hegemonic frame would disappear and begin to erode the legitimacy of the frame. Interestingly, although the abolition of work disincentives and ‘making work pay’ have been the utmost priority in the policy process since the 1990 recession, cabinets have not dared to openly discuss the work disincentives that cash-for-care creates.</p>
</sec>
<sec id="sec3-6">
<title>Pronatalism</title>
<p>Pronatalism has in many countries been the most important argument for family policy. For example, in the beginning of the 1960s the Swedish Conservatives could not find anything good in cash-for-care other than its effectiveness in increasing birth rates (Hinnfors,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref30">1992</xref>
: 99). However, in Sweden, pronatalism is not strongly used in arguing for home care allowance. Yet some Swedish writers criticising the ‘Freedom of choice reform’ have emphasised the pronatalism issue and warned that the implementation of cash-for-care may have detrimental consequences for the Swedish fertility rate (Duvander
<italic>et al</italic>
.,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref9">2008</xref>
).</p>
<p>In Finland, especially in the rhetoric of the non-socialist parties, family policy measures that were supposed to increase birth rates traditionally have had a strong foothold (Nätkin,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref54">1997</xref>
). After a slight decline in the 1970s and 1980s, pronatalism has regained its legitimacy in the wake of the global discussion on ageing populations. In the Swedish debate, the emphasis seems to have been more on the quality of care than on demographics, and solutions have been sought for better ways of combining work and employment. In the Finnish debate, the discourse has been more affected by pronatalism.</p>
</sec>
</sec>
<sec id="sec4" sec-type="discussion">
<title>Discussion</title>
<p>Over the past decade, we have witnessed a growing number of ‘ideational’ studies, stressing the impact of verbal concepts and discourses in the construction of social reality, and creating possibilities and hindrances for subsequent actions. Although our interest was in ideas and discourses, we did not want to neglect social structures or classes. We share Weber's (
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref69">1989</xref>
[1904–5]: 90) and Geertz's (
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref21">1972</xref>
: 314) notions that ideas that can become effective forces in history must be implemented by predominant actors, and someone must revere, defend and impose them. Our analysis indicates that the framing of political alternatives has played and still plays a central role in political debates on child-care policies in Sweden and Finland. Although politicians use the same basic ‘virtues’ in both countries, their content or interpretation was different. The central findings are presented in
<xref ref-type="table" rid="tab2">Table 2</xref>
.
<table-wrap position="float" id="tab2">
<label>TABLE 2.</label>
<caption>
<p>Freedom to choose or trap for women: hegemonic frames of cash-for-care in Finland and Sweden.</p>
</caption>
<graphic xlink:href="S0047279409003067_tab2" mime-subtype="gif"></graphic>
</table-wrap>
</p>
<p>In Finland, supporters of cash-for-care (mainly the Centre and Conservative parties) managed to create a number of important positive connotations, whereas in Sweden the opponents (mainly the Social Democrats) launched the influential ‘trap for women’ slogan. In Finland, gender equality was not as clearly emphasised as in Sweden, and the recognition and value of work at home was more pronounced, whereas in Sweden allowance was interpreted as propping up the old-fashioned family model. In the dominant Finnish interpretation, care allowance is portrayed as an effective means of decreasing the dependence of families on the market. The Finnish frame is more family-oriented, while the Swedish frame stresses more individuality and, in Frazer's (
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref18">2003</xref>
) terms, recognises the working citizen model.</p>
<p>In Finland, freedom meant the possibility for families to choose between different forms of care and to decide for themselves what they needed, while in Sweden freedom was understood as the possibility to fulfil oneself both in working life and in parenting at home. Thus in Sweden women's double burden was solved by the equal right to parenthood and work, whereas the solution in Finland was ‘either-or’.</p>
<p>The costs of social policy have, on the whole, been a central theme in the Finnish non-socialist rhetoric. Austerity has always been an over-arching meta-frame in the Finnish political discourse (Kosonen,
<xref ref-type="bibr" rid="ref40">1993</xref>
), and cash-for-care is seen as much cheaper than institutional day care. Furthermore, because of the
<italic>politics of responsibility</italic>
versus
<italic>politics of distribution</italic>
frames, the Finnish socialists have not been able to counter-manoeuvre the bourgeois ideas by promising improvements in the parental leave scheme, which has been an effective strategy for the SAP in Sweden. According to the Swedish socialist frame, public day care is a more rational and cheaper alternative than home care. One of its advantages is also the quality of the nurturing, which would pay off the costs at some future point. What initially appears to be a cost is in the long run an investment.</p>
<p>In political debate, politicians constantly refer to children's best interests. However, the interpretation of what is the best for children varies substantially. According to the leftist Swedish frame, day-care centres organised by public authorities offer the most inspiring preconditions for development, and they even out inequalities caused by family backgrounds. In Finland, the issue is seen differently: the ideal for children is love and care received at home.
<italic>Home</italic>
care, with all its imaginable good characteristics, was contrasted against
<italic>institutional</italic>
care, which was suspected of being bureaucratic and completely devoid of emotion. When the three ‘good elements’ of the Finnish non-socialist parties – child welfare, justice and freedom of choice – were united with a proposal which was economically cheaper and had the effect of decreasing unemployment, child home care became a strong trump card for the parties pursuing it.</p>
<p>This discussion has dealt exclusively with hegemonic battles between political parties, which most welfare state analyses treat as unitary actors: Social Democrats wanted this, whereas the Conservatives wanted that. Our historical review clearly indicates that political parties have vacillated in their policy preferences and, on occasion, done complete U-turns. To a certain extent, we can challenge the ‘constant cause’ and ‘unitary actor’ explanations in comparative welfare research. These modes of explanation assume that a given causality is equally relevant for all points in time; that is, some political force, say the Social Democrats, has had the same impact and the same ideas about social policy for decades (cf.
<xref ref-type="table" rid="tab1">Table 1</xref>
). The U-turns in political orientations indicate that political parties are not such unitary and monolithic actors as often supposed. Parties have their internal hegemonic struggles, and after the healing of these fissures ‘the constitutional moment’ paves the way for subsequent policy-making.</p>
</sec>
</body>
<back>
<ack id="ack1">
<title>Acknowledgement</title>
<p>We would like to thank Paula Blomquist, Walter Korpi and the anonymous referees of the
<italic>Journal of Social Policy</italic>
.</p>
</ack>
<fn-group>
<title>Note</title>
<fn id="fn1" symbol="1">
<label>1</label>
<p>Interview in the social-democrat newspaper
<italic>Demari</italic>
(28 October 1997) with the Cabinet Minister for Social Affairs and Health, Sinikka Mönkäre (a Social Democrat), where she called for abolishing the home care allowance.</p>
</fn>
</fn-group>
<ref-list>
<title>References</title>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref1">
<name>
<surname>Anttonen</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1999</year>
),
<source>Lasten kotihoidon tuki suomalaisessa perhepolitiikassa</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Kansaneläkelaitos</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref2">
<name>
<surname>Beland</surname>
<given-names>D.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2005</year>
),
<source>Social Security: History and Politics from the New Deal to the Privatization Debate</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Lawrence</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>University Press of Kansas</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref4">
<name>
<surname>Bergqvist</surname>
<given-names>C.</given-names>
</name>
,
<name>
<surname>Borchorst</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
,
<name>
<surname>Christensen</surname>
<given-names>A.-D.</given-names>
</name>
,
<name>
<surname>Raaum</surname>
<given-names>N.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Styrkasdotter</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(eds.) (
<year>1999</year>
),
<source>Likestilte demokratier? Kjønn og politikk i Norden</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Oslo</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Universitetsforlaget</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref5">
<name>
<surname>Björnberg</surname>
<given-names>U.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2002</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Ideology and choice between work and care: Swedish family policy for working parents</article-title>
’,
<source>Critical Social Policy</source>
,
<volume>22</volume>
:
<fpage>33</fpage>
<lpage>52</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref6">
<name>
<surname>Bourdieu</surname>
<given-names>P.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
),
<source>Language and Symbolic Power</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cambridge, MA</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Harvard University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref7">
<name>
<surname>Burestam Linder</surname>
<given-names>S.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1983</year>
),
<source>Den hjärtlösa välfärdsstaten</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Lund</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Timbrå</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref8">
<name>
<surname>Cambell</surname>
<given-names>J.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1998</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Institutional analysis and the role of ideas in political economy</article-title>
’,
<source>Theory and Society</source>
,
<volume>27</volume>
:
<fpage>377</fpage>
<lpage>409</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref9">
<name>
<surname>Duvander</surname>
<given-names>A.-Z.</given-names>
</name>
,
<name>
<surname>Ferrarini</surname>
<given-names>T.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Thalberg</surname>
<given-names>S.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2008</year>
), ‘Sweden towards a new model of family policy?’,
<source>Future International, Framtider International Edition</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Institute for Futures Studies, Future International</publisher-name>
, available from
<uri xlink:href="http://www.framtidsstudier.se/eng/redirect.asp?p=2663">http://www.framtidsstudier.se/eng/redirect.asp?p=2663</uri>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref10">
<name>
<surname>Ellingsæter</surname>
<given-names>A. L.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2007</year>
), ‘
<article-title>“Old” and “new” politics of time to care: three Norwegian reforms</article-title>
’,
<source>Journal of European Social Policy</source>
,
<volume>17</volume>
:
<fpage>49</fpage>
<lpage>60</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref11">
<name>
<surname>Elster</surname>
<given-names>J.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1993</year>
),
<source>Political Psychology</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cambridge</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Cambridge University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref12">
<name>
<surname>Eriksson</surname>
<given-names>N.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1964</year>
),
<source>Bara en hemmafru: Ett debattinlägg om kvinnan i familjen</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Forum</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref13">
<name>
<surname>Ervasti</surname>
<given-names>H.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1996</year>
),
<source>Kenen vastuu?</source>
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Stakes</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref14">
<name>
<surname>Fairclough</surname>
<given-names>N.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1989</year>
),
<source>Language and Power</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Singapore</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Longman</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref15">
<name>
<surname>Fairclough</surname>
<given-names>N.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1992</year>
),
<source>Discourse and Social Change</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cambridge</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Polity Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref16">
<name>
<surname>Ferrarini</surname>
<given-names>T.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2006</year>
),
<source>Families, States and Labour Markets: Institutions, Causes and Consequences of Family Policy in Post-War Welfare States</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cheltenham</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Edward Elgar</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref17">
<name>
<surname>Foucault</surname>
<given-names>M.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1986</year>
),
<source>The Archaeology of Knowledge</source>
,
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Tavistock</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref18">
<name>
<surname>Frazer</surname>
<given-names>N.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
), ‘Social justice in the age of identity politics’, in
<name>
<surname>Frazer</surname>
<given-names>N.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Honneth</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(eds.),
<source>Redistribution or Recognition</source>
?
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Verso</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref19">
<name>
<surname>Gamson</surname>
<given-names>W. A.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Modigliani</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1987</year>
), ‘
<article-title>The changing culture of affirmative action</article-title>
’,
<source>Research in Political Sociology</source>
,
<volume>3</volume>
:
<fpage>137</fpage>
–77.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref20">
<name>
<surname>Gamson</surname>
<given-names>W. A.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Modigliani</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1989</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Media discourse and public opinion on nuclear power: a constructionist approach</article-title>
’,
<source>American Journal of Sociology</source>
,
<volume>92</volume>
:
<fpage>1</fpage>
<lpage>37</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref21">
<name>
<surname>Geerts</surname>
<given-names>C.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1972</year>
),
<source>The Interpretation of Cultures</source>
,
<publisher-loc>New York</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Basic Books</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref22">
<name>
<surname>Giddens</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1991</year>
),
<source>Modernity and Self-Identity</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stanford, CA</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Stanford University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref23">
<name>
<surname>Gornick</surname>
<given-names>J.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Meyers</surname>
<given-names>M.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
),
<source>Families that Work: Policies for Reconciling Parenthood and Employment</source>
,
<publisher-loc>New York</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>The Russell Sage Foundation</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref24">
<name>
<surname>Gramsci</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1971</year>
),
<source>Selections from the Prison Notebooks</source>
,
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Lawrence & Wishart</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref25">
<name>
<surname>Haataja</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Nyberg</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2006</year>
), ‘Diverging paths? The dual-earner/dual-carer model in Finland and Sweden’, in
<name>
<surname>Ellingsæter</surname>
<given-names>A. L.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Leira</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(eds.),
<source>Politicising Parenthood in Scandinavia: Gender Relations in Welfare States</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Bristol</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Policy Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref27">
<name>
<surname>Hatje</surname>
<given-names>A.-K.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1974</year>
),
<source>Befolkningsfrågan och välfärden: Debatten om familjepolitik och nativitetsökning under 1930- och 1940-talen</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Allmänna Förlaget</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref28">
<name>
<surname>Hiilamo</surname>
<given-names>H.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2002</year>
),
<source>The Rise and Fall of Nordic Family Policy? Historical Development and Changes during the 1990s in Sweden and Finland</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Stakes</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref29">
<name>
<surname>Hiilamo</surname>
<given-names>H.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
), ‘Perhetuet ja pienten lasten hoito – Porvari- ja vasemmistohallitusten perhepolitiikan vertailua 1990–2003’, in
<name>
<surname>Ritakallio</surname>
<given-names>V.-M.</given-names>
</name>
(ed.),
<source>Riskit, Instituutiot ja tuotokset</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Sosiaalipoliittinen yhdistys</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref30">
<name>
<surname>Hinnfors</surname>
<given-names>J.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1992</year>
),
<source>Familjepolitik. Samhällsförändringar och partistrategier 1960–1990</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Almqvist & Wiksell International</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref31">
<name>
<surname>Hirdman</surname>
<given-names>Y.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1988</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Alva Myrdal – en studie i feminism</article-title>
’,
<source>Kvinnovetenskaplig tidskrift</source>
,
<volume>9</volume>
:
<fpage>15</fpage>
<lpage>31</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref32">
<name>
<surname>Hirdman</surname>
<given-names>Y.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1989</year>
),
<source>Att lägga livet till rätta – studier i svensk folkhemspolitik</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Carlssons</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref33">
<name>
<surname>Hirdman</surname>
<given-names>Y.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1997</year>
), ‘Social planning under rational control: social engineering in Sweden in the 1930s and 1940s’, in
<name>
<surname>Kettunen</surname>
<given-names>P.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Eskola</surname>
<given-names>H.</given-names>
</name>
(eds.),
<source>Models, Modernity and the Myrdals</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Renvall Institute</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref34">
<name>
<surname>Hirdman</surname>
<given-names>Y.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1998</year>
), ‘State policy and gender contracts: the Swedish experience’, in
<name>
<surname>Drew</surname>
<given-names>E.</given-names>
</name>
,
<name>
<surname>Emerek</surname>
<given-names>R.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Mahon</surname>
<given-names>E.</given-names>
</name>
(eds.),
<source>Women, Work and the Family in Europe</source>
,
<publisher-loc>New York</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Routledge</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref35">
<name>
<surname>Hirdman</surname>
<given-names>Y.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2006</year>
),
<source>Det tänkande hjärtat: Boken om Alva Myrdal</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Ordfront: Stockholm</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref36">
<name>
<surname>Kangas</surname>
<given-names>O.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1986</year>
),
<source>Luokkaintressit ja hyvinvointivaltio</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Helsingin kauppakorkeakoulun julkaisuja D-84</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref37">
<name>
<surname>Korpi</surname>
<given-names>W.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1978</year>
),
<source>Working Class in Welfare Capitalism: Work, Unions and Politics in Sweden</source>
,
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Routledge & Kegan Paul</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref38">
<name>
<surname>Korpi</surname>
<given-names>W.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Palme</surname>
<given-names>J.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
), ‘
<article-title>New politics and class politics in the context of austerity and globalization: welfare state regress in 18 countries, 1975–95</article-title>
’,
<source>American Political Science Review</source>
,
<volume>90</volume>
:
<fpage>425</fpage>
–46.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref40">
<name>
<surname>Kosonen</surname>
<given-names>P.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1993</year>
),
<source>Pohjoismaiset mallit murroksessa</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Tampere</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Vastapaino</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref41">
<name>
<surname>Laclau</surname>
<given-names>E.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Mouffe</surname>
<given-names>C.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1985</year>
),
<source>Hegemony and Socialist Strategy</source>
,
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Verso</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref42">
<name>
<surname>Lane</surname>
<given-names>J.-E.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Ersson</surname>
<given-names>S.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2002</year>
), ‘The Nordic countries: contention, compromise and corporatism’, in
<name>
<surname>Colomer</surname>
<given-names>J.</given-names>
</name>
. (ed.),
<source>Political Institutions in Europe</source>
,
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Routledge</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref43">
<name>
<surname>Larsson</surname>
<given-names>M.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Hägglund</surname>
<given-names>G.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2007</year>
), ‘Sahlins politik blir änny mer tvingande’,
<italic>Aftonbladet</italic>
, 2 May.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref44">
<name>
<surname>Leira</surname>
<given-names>A.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2002</year>
),
<source>Working Parents and the Welfare State: Family Change and Policy Reform in Scandinavia</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cambridge</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Cambridge University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref45">
<name>
<surname>Lieberman</surname>
<given-names>R. C.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2002</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Ideas, institutions, and political order: explaining political change</article-title>
’,
<source>American Political Science Review</source>
,
<volume>96</volume>
:
<fpage>697</fpage>
<lpage>712</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref47">
<name>
<surname>Lundberg</surname>
<given-names>U.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
),
<source>Juvelen i kronan: Socialdemokraterna och den allmänna pensionen</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Hjalmarson & Högberg</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref48">
<name>
<surname>Lundqvist</surname>
<given-names>Å.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2007</year>
),
<source>Familjen i den svenska modellen</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Umeå</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Borea</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref49">
<name>
<surname>Lindberg</surname>
<given-names>I.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2001</year>
),
<source>Den nya familjens tid</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>LO</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref50">
<name>
<surname>Mahoney</surname>
<given-names>J.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2000</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Path dependence in historical sociology</article-title>
’,
<source>Theory and Society</source>
,
<volume>29</volume>
:
<fpage>507</fpage>
–48.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref51">
<name>
<surname>Majone</surname>
<given-names>G.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1989</year>
),
<source>Evidence, Argument and Persuasion in the Policy Process</source>
,
<publisher-loc>New Haven</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Yale University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref52">
<name>
<surname>Morgan</surname>
<given-names>K. J.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Zippel</surname>
<given-names>K.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Paid to care: the origins and effects of care leave in Western Europe</article-title>
’,
<source>International Studies in Gender, State and Society</source>
,
<volume>10</volume>
:
<fpage>49</fpage>
<lpage>95</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref53">
<name>
<surname>Nygård</surname>
<given-names>M.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
),
<source>Välfärdsstaten, partierna och marknaden: den välfärdsideologiska förändringen inom fyra finländska partier under 1990-talet</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Åbo</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Åbo Akademis förlag</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref54">
<name>
<surname>Nätkin</surname>
<given-names>R.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1997</year>
),
<source>Kamppailu suomalaisesta äitiydestä. Maternalismi, väestöpolitiikka ja naisten kertomukset</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Tampere</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Gaudeamus</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref55">
<name>
<surname>Pfau-Effinger</surname>
<given-names>B.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2005</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Culture and welfare state policies: reflections on a complex interrelation</article-title>
’,
<source>Journal of Social Policy</source>
,
<volume>34</volume>
:
<fpage>3</fpage>
<lpage>20</lpage>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref57">
<name>
<surname>Sahlin</surname>
<given-names>M.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2007</year>
), ‘Nej, det cementerar ojämställdheten!’,
<italic>Aftonbladet</italic>
2, May.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref58">
<name>
<surname>Sainsbury</surname>
<given-names>D.</given-names>
</name>
(ed.) (
<year>1999</year>
),
<source>Gender and Welfare State Regimes</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Oxford</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Oxford University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="thesis" id="ref59">
<name>
<surname>Sakaranaho</surname>
<given-names>T.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1992</year>
), ‘Lasten kotihoidon tuki’, Unpublished Masters thesis, Department of Social Policy, University of Tampere.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref60">
<name>
<surname>de Saussure</surname>
<given-names>F.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1974</year>
),
<source>Course in General Linguistics</source>
,
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Fontana</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="journal" id="ref61">
<name>
<surname>Schmidt</surname>
<given-names>V.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2002</year>
), ‘
<article-title>Does discourse matter in the politics of welfare state adjustment?</article-title>
’,
<source>Comparative Political Studies</source>
,
<volume>35</volume>
:
<fpage>168</fpage>
–93.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref62">
<name>
<surname>Spector</surname>
<given-names>M.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Kitsuse</surname>
<given-names>I.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1989</year>
),
<source>Constructing Social Problems</source>
,
<publisher-loc>New York</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>DeGruyter</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref63">
<name>
<surname>Steinmo</surname>
<given-names>S.</given-names>
</name>
,
<name>
<surname>Thelen</surname>
<given-names>K.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Longstreth</surname>
<given-names>F.</given-names>
</name>
(eds.) (
<year>1992</year>
),
<source>Structuring Politics</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cambridge</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Cambridge University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref64">
<name>
<surname>Streeck</surname>
<given-names>W.</given-names>
</name>
and
<name>
<surname>Thelen</surname>
<given-names>K.</given-names>
</name>
(eds.) (
<year>2004</year>
),
<source>Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Economies</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Oxford</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Oxford University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref65">
<name>
<surname>Sulkunen</surname>
<given-names>I.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1989</year>
),
<source>Naisen kutsumus: Miina Sillanpää ja sukupuolten maailmojen erkaantuminen</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Hanki ja Jää</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref66">
<name>
<surname>Thelen</surname>
<given-names>K.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2004</year>
),
<source>How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cambridge</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Cambridge University Press</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref67">
<name>
<surname>Timonen</surname>
<given-names>V.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>2003</year>
),
<source>Restructuring the Welfare State: Globalization and Social Policy Reforms in Finland and Sweden</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Cheltenham</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Edward Elgar</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref68">
<name>
<surname>Tyyskä</surname>
<given-names>V.</given-names>
</name>
(
<year>1995</year>
),
<source>The Politics of Caring and the Welfare State</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Helsinki</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Finnish Academy of Science, Series B</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref69">
<name>
<surname>Weber</surname>
<given-names>M.</given-names>
</name>
<year>1989</year>
[1904–05],
<source>The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism</source>
,
<publisher-loc>London</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Allen & Unwin</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
</ref-list>
<ref-list>
<title>Parliamentary sources</title>
<ref-list>
<title>
<italic>Finland</italic>
</title>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref70">
<collab>Financial motion 569/1981</collab>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref71">
<collab>Petitionary motion no 288/1947</collab>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref72">
<collab>Petitionary motion no 1493/1982</collab>
.</citation>
</ref>
</ref-list>
<ref-list>
<title>
<italic>Sweden</italic>
</title>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref74">
<collab>Preliminary debate protocol 4 20/1</collab>
; (
<year>1965</year>
).</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref75">
<collab>Motion no 98/1997</collab>
: Ub211.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="other" id="ref76">
<collab>Socialdepartmentet</collab>
(
<year>2007</year>
), ‘En valfrihetsreform för familjer snart verklighet’,
<italic>Pressmeddelande</italic>
7 March.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref77">
<collab>SOU</collab>
(
<year>1966</year>
): 59,
<source>Remissyttranden över 1965 års långtidsutrednings huvudrapport Svensk ekonomi 1966–1970 med utblick mot 1980</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Statens Offentliga Utredningar</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref78">
<collab>SOU</collab>
(
<year>1972</year>
):34,
<source>Familjestöd</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Statens Offentliga Utredningar</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
<ref>
<citation citation-type="book" id="ref79">
<collab>SOU</collab>
(
<year>1994</year>
):25,
<source>Report of the Social Committee 1993/1994</source>
,
<publisher-loc>Stockholm</publisher-loc>
:
<publisher-name>Statens Offentliga Utredningar</publisher-name>
.</citation>
</ref>
</ref-list>
</ref-list>
</back>
</article>
</istex:document>
</istex:metadataXml>
<mods version="3.6">
<titleInfo>
<title>Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</title>
</titleInfo>
<titleInfo type="alternative">
<title>HEIKKI HIILAMO AND OLLI KANGAS</title>
</titleInfo>
<titleInfo type="alternative" contentType="CDATA">
<title>Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden</title>
</titleInfo>
<name type="personal">
<namePart type="given">HEIKKI</namePart>
<namePart type="family">HIILAMO</namePart>
<affiliation>Vice Director, Diaconia University of Applied Sciences/Diak South, Sturenkatu 2, 00510 Helsinki, Finland email: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</affiliation>
<affiliation>E-mail: heikki.hiilamo@diak.fi</affiliation>
<role>
<roleTerm type="text">author</roleTerm>
</role>
</name>
<name type="personal">
<namePart type="given">OLLI</namePart>
<namePart type="family">KANGAS</namePart>
<affiliation>Research Professor, Social Insurance Institution of Finland, KELA/Research, PO Box 450, 00101 Helsinki, Finland email: olli.kangas@kela.fi</affiliation>
<affiliation>E-mail: olli.kangas@kela.fi</affiliation>
<role>
<roleTerm type="text">author</roleTerm>
</role>
</name>
<typeOfResource>text</typeOfResource>
<genre type="research-article" displayLabel="research-article" authority="ISTEX" authorityURI="https://content-type.data.istex.fr" valueURI="https://content-type.data.istex.fr/ark:/67375/XTP-1JC4F85T-7">research-article</genre>
<originInfo>
<publisher>Cambridge University Press</publisher>
<place>
<placeTerm type="text">Cambridge, UK</placeTerm>
</place>
<dateIssued encoding="w3cdtf">2009</dateIssued>
<copyrightDate encoding="w3cdtf">2009</copyrightDate>
</originInfo>
<language>
<languageTerm type="code" authority="iso639-2b">eng</languageTerm>
<languageTerm type="code" authority="rfc3066">en</languageTerm>
</language>
<abstract type="normal">Debates on welfare reforms have revolved around institutional inertias with the emphasis on institutions as structures. We argue that political discourses work in the same vein and create continuities constraining the array of possible policy options – political frames as carriers of institutional inertia and path dependence. The data are based on political debates on child home care in Finland and Sweden. The ‘trap for women’ frame became dominant in the Swedish discourse, while in Finland ‘freedom to choose’ has been hegemonic. According to the Swedish frame, public day care offers children the best preconditions for later development and enhances social equality, whereas in Finland care at home with all its positive characteristics was contrasted with bureaucratic institutional care. The article highlights how politicians have used these hegemonic discourses to maintain the legitimacy of certain policy options.</abstract>
<relatedItem type="host">
<titleInfo>
<title>Journal of Social Policy</title>
</titleInfo>
<titleInfo type="abbreviated">
<title>J. Soc. Pol.</title>
</titleInfo>
<genre type="journal" authority="ISTEX" authorityURI="https://publication-type.data.istex.fr" valueURI="https://publication-type.data.istex.fr/ark:/67375/JMC-0GLKJH51-B">journal</genre>
<identifier type="ISSN">0047-2794</identifier>
<identifier type="eISSN">1469-7823</identifier>
<identifier type="PublisherID">JSP</identifier>
<part>
<date>2009</date>
<detail type="volume">
<caption>vol.</caption>
<number>38</number>
</detail>
<detail type="issue">
<caption>no.</caption>
<number>3</number>
</detail>
<extent unit="pages">
<start>457</start>
<end>475</end>
<total>19</total>
</extent>
</part>
</relatedItem>
<identifier type="istex">6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D</identifier>
<identifier type="ark">ark:/67375/6GQ-VQKRR6G9-6</identifier>
<identifier type="DOI">10.1017/S0047279409003067</identifier>
<identifier type="PII">S0047279409003067</identifier>
<identifier type="ArticleID">00306</identifier>
<accessCondition type="use and reproduction" contentType="copyright">Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009</accessCondition>
<recordInfo>
<recordContentSource authority="ISTEX" authorityURI="https://loaded-corpus.data.istex.fr" valueURI="https://loaded-corpus.data.istex.fr/ark:/67375/XBH-G3RCRD03-V">cambridge</recordContentSource>
<recordOrigin>Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2009</recordOrigin>
</recordInfo>
</mods>
<json:item>
<extension>json</extension>
<original>false</original>
<mimetype>application/json</mimetype>
<uri>https://api.istex.fr/document/6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D/metadata/json</uri>
</json:item>
</metadata>
<annexes>
<json:item>
<extension>gif</extension>
<original>true</original>
<mimetype>image/gif</mimetype>
<uri>https://api.istex.fr/document/6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D/annexes/gif</uri>
</json:item>
</annexes>
<serie></serie>
</istex>
</record>

Pour manipuler ce document sous Unix (Dilib)

EXPLOR_STEP=$WICRI_ROOT/Wicri/Santé/explor/EdenteV2/Data/Istex/Corpus
HfdSelect -h $EXPLOR_STEP/biblio.hfd -nk 003522 | SxmlIndent | more

Ou

HfdSelect -h $EXPLOR_AREA/Data/Istex/Corpus/biblio.hfd -nk 003522 | SxmlIndent | more

Pour mettre un lien sur cette page dans le réseau Wicri

{{Explor lien
   |wiki=    Wicri/Santé
   |area=    EdenteV2
   |flux=    Istex
   |étape=   Corpus
   |type=    RBID
   |clé=     ISTEX:6BA400194225E7043DCE8214AFBF6BB083D1457D
   |texte=   Trap for Women or Freedom to Choose? The Struggle over Cash for Child Care Schemes in Finland and Sweden
}}

Wicri

This area was generated with Dilib version V0.6.32.
Data generation: Thu Nov 30 15:26:48 2017. Site generation: Tue Mar 8 16:36:20 2022